Перевод английских текстов различной тематики
Характер торговой деятельности. Преимущества и недостатки полной долларизации. Контракт. Форма доверенности на управление бизнесом. The Nature of Merchandising Activities. Full Dollarization. The Pros and Cons. Form of Power to Manage a Business.
Рубрика | Иностранные языки и языкознание |
Вид | дипломная работа |
Язык | английский |
Дата добавления | 20.12.2008 |
Размер файла | 318,2 K |
Отправить свою хорошую работу в базу знаний просто. Используйте форму, расположенную ниже
Студенты, аспиранты, молодые ученые, использующие базу знаний в своей учебе и работе, будут вам очень благодарны.
The trial balance includes these unique accounts for merchandising activ-ities: Merchandise Inventory, Sales, Sales Returns and Allowances, Sales Dis-counts, Purchases, Purchases Returns and Allowances, Purchases Discounts, and Transportation-In. Their presence in the ledger causes the closing entries to be slightly different from the ones described in Chapter 4. However, the process still consists of four steps.
Step 1--Record the Ending Inventory and Close the Temporary Accounts That Have Credit Balances
The first step accomplishes two goals: First, it adds the $21,000 cost of the ending inventory to the balance of the Merchandise Inventory account. Sec-ond, it closes the temporary accounts that have credit balances, including the Sales account and the two contra-purchases accounts. The first closing entry for Meg's Mart is
Dec. 31 Merchandise Inventory…………………..21,000.00
Sales ……………….. 321,000.00
Purchases Returns and Allowances…… 1,500.00
Purchases Discounts ………………. 4,200.00
Income Summary ………………. 347,700.00
To close temporary accounts with credit
balances and record the ending inventory
Posting this entry gives zero balances to the three temporary accounts that had credit balances in the adjusted trial balance. It also momentarily increases the balance of the Merchandise Inventory account to $40,000. How-ever the next entry reduces the balance of this account.
Step 2--Remove the Beginning Inventory and Close the Temporary Accounts That Have Debit Balances
The second step also accomplishes two results: First, it subtracts the cost of the beginning inventory from the Merchandise Inventory account. Second, it closes the temporary accounts that have debit balances, including the ex-pense accounts, the two contra-sales accounts, the Purchases account, and the Transportation-In account. The second closing entry for Meg's Mart is
Dec. 31 Income Summary ………………………326,200.00
Merchandise Inventory……………………… 19,000.00
Sales Returns and Allowances………………. 2,000.00
Sales Discounts ……………………… 4,300.00
Purchases ……………………… 235,800.00
Transportation-In ……………………… 2,300.00
Depreciation Expense, Store Equipment….. 3,000.00
Depreciation Expense, Office Equipment…. 700.00
Office Salaries Expense 25,300.00
Sales Salaries Expense………………………. 18,500.00
Insurance Expense ……………………… 600.00
Rent Expense, Office Space………………… 900.00
Rent Expense, Selling Space………………. 8,100.00
Office Supplies Expense…………………… 1,800.00
Store Supplies Expense…………………… 1,200.00
Advertising Expense 2,700.00
To close temporary accounts with debit balances and
to remove the beginning inventory balance
Posting this entry reduces the balance of the Merchandise Inventory account down to $21,000, which is the amount produced by the physical count at De-cember 31,19X2. It also gives zero balances to the 14 temporary accounts that had debit balances.
The following Merchandise Inventory account shows you how the first two closing entries create an ending balance equal to the $21,000 cost provided by the physical count:
Merchandise Inventory Acct. No. 119 |
||||||
Date |
Explanation |
Debit |
Credit |
Balance |
||
19X1 |
||||||
Dec. |
31 |
Ending balance for 19X1 |
19,000.00 |
|||
19X2 |
||||||
Dec. |
31 |
First closing entry |
21,000.00 |
40,000.00 |
||
31 |
Second closing entry (Ending balance for 19X2) |
19,000.00 |
21,000.00 |
As mentioned earlier in the chapter, this account has the $21,000 balance throughout 19X3 until the accounts are closed at the end of that year.
Step 3--Close the Income Summary Account to the Owner's Capital Account
The third closing entry for a merchandising company is the same as the third closing entry for a service company. Specifically, it closes the Income Summary account and updates the balance of the owner's capital account. The third closing entry for Meg's Mart is
Dec. 31 Income Summary………………………………….. 21,500.00
Meg Harlowe, Capital………………………. 21,500.00
To close the Income Summary account
The amount in the entry equals the net income reported on the income statement.
Step 4--Close the Owner's Withdrawals Account to the Owner's Capital Account
The fourth closing entry for a merchandising company is the same as the fourth closing entry for a service company. Specifically, it closes the owner's withdrawals account and reduces the balance of the owner's capital account to the amount shown on the balance sheet. The fourth closing entry for Meg's Mart is
Dec. 31 Meg Harlowe, Capital …………………4,000.00
Meg Harlowe, Withdrawals ………………. 4,000.00
To close the withdrawals account
When this entry is posted, all the temporary accounts are cleared and ready to record events in 19X3. In addition, the owner's capital account has been fully updated to reflect the events of 19X2.
A Work Sheet for a Merchandising Company
Illustration 9 presents a version of the work sheet that the accountant for Meg's Mart could prepare in the process of developing its 19X2 financial state-ments. It differs in two ways from the 10-column work sheet described in Chapter 4.
ILLUSTRATION 9
Work Sheet for Meg's Mart for the Year Ended December 3119X2
№ |
Account |
Unadjusted Trial Balance |
Adjustments |
Income Statement |
Statement of Changes in Owner's Equity and Balance Sheet |
|||||
Dr. |
Cr. |
Dr. |
Cr. |
Dr. |
Cr. |
Dr. |
Cr. |
|||
101 |
Cash |
8,200 |
8,200 |
|||||||
106 |
Accounts receivable |
11,200 |
11,200 |
|||||||
119 |
Merchandise inventory |
19,200 |
19,200 |
21,000 |
21,000 |
|||||
124 |
Office supplies |
2,350 |
(с) 1,800 |
550 |
||||||
125 |
Store supplies |
1,450 |
(b) 1,200 |
250 |
||||||
128 |
Prepaid insurance |
900 |
(a) 600 |
300 |
||||||
163 |
Office equipment |
4,200 |
4,200 |
|||||||
164 |
Accum. Depr., office |
700 |
(e) 700 |
1,400 |
||||||
165 |
Store equipment |
30,000 |
30,000 |
|||||||
166 |
Accum. Depr., store equip. |
3,000 |
(d) 3,000 |
6,000 |
||||||
201 |
Accounts payable |
16,000 |
16,000 |
|||||||
209 |
Salaries payable |
(f) 800 |
800 |
|||||||
301 |
Meg Harlowe, capital |
34,000 |
34,000 |
|||||||
302 |
Meg Harlowe, withdrawals |
4,000 |
4,000 |
|||||||
413 |
Sales |
321,000 |
321,000 |
|||||||
414 |
Sales returns and allow. |
2,000 |
2,000 |
|||||||
415 |
Sales discounts |
4,300 |
4,300 |
|||||||
505 |
Purchases |
235,800 |
235,800 |
|||||||
506 |
Purchases ret. And allow. |
1,500 |
1,500 |
|||||||
507 |
Purchases discounts |
4,200 |
4,200 |
|||||||
508 |
Transportation-in |
2,300 |
2,300 |
|||||||
612 |
Depr. Expense, store |
(d) 3,000 |
3,000 |
|||||||
613 |
Depr. Expense, office |
(e) 700 |
700 |
|||||||
620 |
Office salaries expense |
25,000 |
(f) 300 |
25,300 |
||||||
621 |
Sales salaries expense |
18,000 |
(f) 500 |
18,500 |
||||||
637 |
Insurance expense |
(a) 600 |
600 |
|||||||
641 |
Rent expense, office |
900 |
900 |
|||||||
642 |
Rent expense, selling |
8,100 |
8,100 |
|||||||
650 |
Office supplies expense |
(c) 1,800 |
1,800 |
|||||||
651 |
Store supplies expense |
(b) 1,200 |
1,200 |
|||||||
655 |
Advertising expense |
2,700 |
2,700 |
|||||||
Totals |
380,400 |
380,400 |
8,100 |
8,100 |
326,200 |
347,700 |
79,700 |
58,200 |
||
Net income |
21,500 |
21,500 |
||||||||
Totals |
347,700 |
347,700 |
79,700 |
79,700 |
The first difference is the deletion of the adjusted trial balance columns. This simplification has nothing to do with the fact that Meg's Mart is a retail business. This commonly used format is designed to simplify the work sheet by reducing its size. The omission of the columns causes the accountant to first compute the adjusted balances and then extend them directly into the finan-cial statement columns.
The second difference appears on the line for the Merchandise Inventory account (shown in color). The unadjusted trial balance includes the beginning inventory balance of $19,000. This amount is extended into the debit column for the income statement. Then, the ending balance is entered in the credit column for the income statement and the debit column for the balance sheet. This step allows the cost of goods sold to be included in net income while the correct ending balance is included for the balance sheet.
The adjustments in the work sheet reflect the following economic events:
Expiration of $600 of prepaid insurance.
Consumption of $1,200 of store supplies.
Consumption of $1,800 of office supplies.
Depreciation of the store equipment for $3,000.
Depreciation of the office equipment for $700.
9. Accrual of $300 of unpaid office salaries and $500 of unpaid store salaries.
Once the adjusted amounts are extended into the financial statement col-umns, the accountant can use this information to develop the company's fi-nancial statements.
The Adjusting Entry Approach to Recording the Change in the Merchandise Inventory Account
The previously described closing entry approach to recording the change in the inventory account is widely used in practice. However, it is not the only bookkeeping method that can be applied at the end of the year. One other possible approach records two adjusting journal entries right before the clos-ing entries are prepared. Because these entries are recorded, the first two closing entries do not include changes in the Merchandise Inventory account. This adjusting entry approach is preferred by some accountants. It is also used by computerized accounting systems that allow only temporary accounts to be affected by closing entries.
The Adjusting Entries
Under this adjusting approach, Meg's Mart removes the beginning balance from the Merchandise Inventory account by recording this adjusting entry at the end of 19X2:
Dec. 31 Income Summary……………………19,000.00
Merchandise Inventory…………. 19,000.00
To remove the beginning balance from
the Merchandise Inventory account.
This second adjusting entry produces the correct ending balance in the Mer-chandise Inventory account:
Dec. 31 Merchandise Inventory ……………21,000.00
Income Summary …….…………. 21,000.00
To insert the correct ending balance
into the Merchandise Inventory account.
After this entry is posted, the Merchandise Inventory account has a $21,000 debit balance. In addition, the Income Summary account has a $2,000 credit balance.
The Closing Entries
If the two adjusting entries for inventory are used, the closing entries differ only by not including the Merchandise Inventory account. Thus, Meg's Mart records the following two closing entries for 19X2 under the adjusting entry approach:
Dec. 31 Sales ………………………………321,000.00
Purchases Returns and Allowances …1,000.00
Purchases Discounts ……… 4,200.00
Income Summary ……… 326,700.00
To close temporary accounts with
credit balances.
Dec. 31 Income Summary …………………… 307,200.00
Sales Returns and Allowances…………….. 2,000.00
Sales Discounts …………………. 4,300.00
Purchases …………………. 235,800.00
Transportation-In ………………… 2,300.00
Depreciation Expense, Store Equipment….. 3,000.00
Depreciation Expense, Office Equipment… 700.00
Office Salaries Expense ………………… 25,300.00
Sales Salaries Expense ………………….. 18,500.00
Insurance Expense ………………… 600.00
Rent Expense, Office Space……………….. 900.00
Rent Expense, Selling Space……………… 8,100.00
Office Supplies Expense ………………… 1,800.00
Store Supplies Expense…………………… 1,200.00
Advertising Expense ……………….. 2,700.00
To close temporary accounts with debit balances
The third and fourth entries are the same as before, although the amount debited to the Income Summary account is now based on four previous entries instead of two:
Dec. 31 Income Summary…………………………21,500.00
Meg Harlowe, Capital……………………. 21,500.00
To close the Income Summary account.
Meg Harlowe, Capital………………………… 4,000.00
Meg Harlowe, Withdrawals…………… 4,000.00
To close the withdrawals account.
The Adjusting Entry Approach and the Work Sheet. If the accountant uses the adjusting entry approach to update the inventory account, the two adjust-ments are included in the adjustments columns in the work sheet, and a line for the Income Summary account is inserted at the bottom of the work sheet. This procedure is not demonstrated here.
Using the Information-- The Acid-Test Ratio
You have learned in this chapter that a company's current assets may include a merchandise inventory. Thus, you can now understand that a major part of a company's current assets may not be immediately available for paying its ex-isting liabilities. In effect, the inventory must be sold and the accounts receiv-able must be collected before cash is available. As a result, the current may not provide a complete description of a company's ability to pay its current liabilities.
To deal with this limitation, financial statement users often calculate the acid-test ratio to assess the company's ability to settle its current debts with its existing assets. The acid-test ratio is similar to the current ratio, but differs because it focuses on the company's immediate future.
The acid-test ratio is calculated just like the current ratio except that its numerator omits inventory and prepaid expenses. The prepaid expenses are omitted because they are not usually converted into cash quickly. The remaining current assets (cash, short-term investments, and receivables) are called the company's quick assets. The formula for the ratio is
The acid-test ratio for Meg's Mart is computed as follows:
In contrast, the current ratio (current assets/current liabilities) for Meg's Mart has this value:
The difference between these two ratio values describes how the company's inventory and prepaid expenses affect its ability to pay short-term obligations with existing resources.
As an approximate rule of thumb, an acid-test ratio value of at least 1.0 suggests that the company is not likely to face a liquidity crisis in the near future. However, a value lower than 1.0 is not necessarily threatening if the company can generate adequate cash from sales or the accounts payable are not due until later in the year. On the other hand, a value higher than 1.0 may hide a liquidity crisis if the payables are due at once but the receivables are scheduled to be collected late in the year. These possibilities reinforce the point that a single ratio is seldom enough to indicate strength or weakness. However, it can identify areas that the analyst should look into more deeply.
Part 2.
Back to basis
In these less exuberant times, managers need to remember a few old-fashioned virtues, says Tim Hindie.
If bad times make good leaders, America is due for a host of them. The recession that began in March last year and the terro-rist attacks on September 11th made 2001 an unforgettably awful year. At such times people react strangely. Some are frozen in indecision while others act with unneces-sary haste. Across large corporations, such behaviour, multiplied many times, can be disastrous. At times of crisis, having the right people in the right place is vital. In a boom there is enough fat to absorb some bad judgment; in a recession good man-agement becomes a survival issue.
Dave Young, head of the Boston Con-sulting Group's Boston office, maintains that for many companies the downturn will turn out to be a blessing. “It means that, increasingly, value in the capital mar-kets will accrue not to irrational exuber-ance' or to sector hype,” he says, “but to good management.” But what, in such cir-cumstances, constitutes good manage-ment? It is certainly not something that can be conjured up out of the blue. Companies that have it now had it in good times too, and found it useful then; the difference is that in today's harsher climate it has be-come essential.
This survey suggests that the core of good management is a set of three old-fashioned virtues that were often forgot-ten in the bubble years, when anything seemed to go. At a minimum, good managers have to meet the following criteria:
be honest;
be frugal;
be prepared.
For many managers, that may sound about as exciting as shopping in Wal-Mart when they have become accustomed to Bloomingdale's. But deep down, they know where they get the better value.
Essential virtues
Being honest, of course, is not just a matter of keeping within the law. Most managers do that, which is why the few who step -outside it receive so much attention. For the law-abiding majority, it is a matter of escaping from self-delusion. That requires setting up systems in which rewards are not related to numbers which can be mas-saged and exaggerated at will.
Above all, it is a matter of being honest about a company's value and its potential. Warren Buffett, the chairman of Berkshire Hathaway and one of the most successful “value creators” in American business over the past 20 years, wrote in one of his celebrated annual letters to shareholders: “We do not want to `ulfillm the price at which Berkshire shares trade…we wish for them to trade in a narrow range centred at [their] intrinsic business value.” Manag-ers need to think about what is their own company' intrinsic business Value”. And so do the investment bankers, analysts, consultants and the rest on the merry go-round of business hype.
In a similar vein, being frugal is not just a matter of cutting costs in a downturn. It is a question of being sparing with resources at all times, of continually looking for new ways to cut costs, and of creating an atmosphere in which waste and excess are unacceptable, no matter what the market conditions. The extremes to which Wal-Mart's managers take this--such as sharing bedrooms on business trips, and being ex-pected to bring back free pens from confer-ences--may be counterproductive, to the point of repelling able managers. But the enduring success of many businesses-- from Andrew Carnegie's and J.P. Morgan's in the 1900s to Warren Buffett's and Sam Walton's today-have been built on a frugality bordering on stinginess.
Full Dollarization The Pros and Cons The Pros and Cons of Full Dollarization
Since the end of the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates nearly thirty years ago, the old dilemma facing countries of finding workable currency exchange arrangements has become more challenging, and the choices have become more varied.
The decision about which exchange rate system to adopt has become more difficult as world trade and capital markets have become more integrated. New problems have emerged, and with them, new answers to the question of the best exchange regime to promote each country's development objectives. The newest of these solutions is full dollarization, under which a country officially abandons its own currency and adopts a more stable currency of another country--most commonly the U.S. dollar--as its legal tender.
From the perspective of any hard currency country, full dollarization may appear more radical than it is: use of the U. S. dollar or another major currency is pervasive to one degree or another in most developing countries, particularly in financial contracts (see Box 1, “What Is Dollarization?”). Full dollarization means taking the next step, from informal, limited dollarization to full, official use of the foreign currency in all transactions.
Box 1. What Is Dollarization?
This pamphlet focuses on full dollarization, or one country officially adopting the currency of another for all financial transactions, except perhaps the need for coins. In considering this choice of exchange regime, two points are important to keep in mind:
· The term dollarization is shorthand for the use of any foreign currency by another country. The issues it raises are identical for the other countries in the region using the South African rand, for example, and they would be for any country of, say, Eastern Europe, considering eventually adopting the euro.
· Most developing countries--as well as transitional economies just adopting market mechanisms--already have a limited, unofficial form of dollarization. To a greater or lesser degree, their residents already hold foreign currency and foreign currency-denominated deposits at domestic banks. In high inflation countries, dollars or some other hard currency may be in widespread use in daily transactions, alongside the local currency.
Such informal dollarization is a response to economic instability and high inflation, and the desire of residents to diversify and protect their assets from the risks of devaluation of their own currencies. It is useful to distinguish between two motives for the demand for foreign currency assets: currency substitution and asset substitution.
In currency substitution foreign assets are used as money, essentially as means of payment and unit of account, and it typically arises under conditions of high inflation or hyperinflation when the high cost of using domestic currency for transactions prompts the public to look for available alternatives. Once the use of foreign currency in transactions becomes accepted, it may not be rapidly abandoned. Remarkably, the increase in dollarization in some Latin American and Asian countries has continued and accelerated in recent years even following successful stabilization.
Asset substitution results from risk and return considerations about domestic and foreign assets. Historically, foreign currency-denominated assets have provided the opportunity of insuring against macroeconomic risks, such as price instability and prolonged depressions in many developing countries. Even under conditions of current stability, foreign currency-denominated assets may still serve this purpose if residents believe there is even a small chance of inflationary relapse.
Important differences exist between informal and full dollarization, presenting transitional problems for governments considering it. All government and private debt under full dollarization is denominated in dollars, and both public and private accounts must be converted to dollars. To make the conversion, countries must set the rate at which old debts, contracts, and financial assets will be converted to dollars.
Finally, the stability promised by dollarization is itself relative, given that the U.S. dollar--or any other hard currency chosen for use by another country--will fluctuate in value against other widely-traded currencies. During the post-Bretton Woods period, these swings have sometimes been large.
Questions About Pegs
Can these advantages offset the costs of a country giving up its own currency? The answers are complex, and in the end turn on each country's specific circumstances. But more and more countries are seriously considering full dollarization as they deal with the changes in the world economy, particularly over the past 20 years.
During the inflation-plagued 1980s, much of the debate over exchange regimes for developing countries centered on the role of exchange rate “pegs”. Countries generally pick from a range of possibilities, including tying their currencies to baskets of other currencies (such as those of their trading partners), indexing their currencies in some way to their own inflation rates, or even banding together in groups, as many French-speaking African nations have through currency unions tied to the French franc.
In the 1990s, global inflation abated and capital mobility and the scale of capital flows increased sharply. While countries welcomed the investment flows, they faced a new threat, as speculative attacks rose in frequency and severity against currencies that capital markets viewed as vulnerable to devaluation.
Generally, the victims of these currency crises were maintaining some sort of pegged exchange rate regime. Consequently, the belief began to emerge that in a world of high capital mobility, exchange rate pegs might themselves attract speculative attacks and that only extreme choices, such as a free float or a currency board were viable. The currency board regime, under which the domestic currency is fully backed by international reserves, is the strongest form of pegged exchange rate option.
Advocates of full dollarization attack both of these choices. Free floats, they argue, are not viable for many developing countries because they risk excessive exchange rate volatility. So far, only the largest developing economies, with relatively advanced financial systems, such as Korea, Brazil, and Mexico, have attempted floating. While experience is limited, these experiments have worked thus far without major disruption.
Meanwhile, currency boards have fallen prey to costly speculative attacks. Argentina and Hong Kong SAR1, using currency boards successfully, nonetheless suffered sharp increases in interest rates and recessions in recent years as speculative attacks spread to them from other countries.
The Appeal of Dollarization
Against this background, then-president Carlos Menem of Argentina suggested in 1999 that Argentina adopt the U.S. dollar as the ultimate solution to its long history of difficulties with monetary and exchange rate policy. In January 2000, Ecuador, in the context of a deep economic and political crisis, adopted the U.S. dollar as its legal tender.
Prominent economists have begun to argue that essentially all developing countries should dollarize, and some industrial countries have even been urged to consider it. Partly prompted by the example of European countries giving up their currencies for the euro, some have suggested that Canada should adopt the U.S. dollar as the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) evolves.
Weighing the pros and cons of full dollarization is complicated by the virtual absence of historical experiences. Panama is the only sizable country with a history of using a foreign currency--the U. S. dollar--as legal tender, and it is fairly small, and has very close historical, political, and economic links to the United States. Even if there were more country experiences to assess, they would have to be over longer periods than is usual for evaluating monetary and exchange rate options. That is because dollarization is nearly permanent, and some of its benefits can be gained only in the long run.
This analysis of full dollarization compares it to its nearest competitor, the currency board. This comparison captures the main implications of dollarization and how its effects differ from those of simply adopting a very firm peg. Furthermore, if the costs and benefits of a currency board turn out to be at least equivalent to dollarization, a currency board would be a simpler and preferable alternative for a country seeking a firmly pegged exchange regime.
The differences between currency boards and dollarization are few, but important. Dollarization's key distinguishing feature is that it is permanent, or nearly so. Reversing dollarization is much more difficult than modifying or abandoning a currency board arrangement. In fact, the largest benefits claimed from dollarization derive from the credibility it carries precisely because it is nearly irreversible. And yet for some countries under particular circumstances, the irreversibility could come at a very high cost.
A government adopting full dollarization gives up the revenue from the loss of seigniorage (see Box 2, What Is Seigniorage?), whereas a currency board country does not. But a dollarizing country, by completely eliminating the risk of currency devaluation, gains lower interest rates on foreign borrowing.
The analysis below examines these issues in more detail. Quantifying the potential savings from lower interest rates turns out to be more complex than it first appears, but the cost of seigniorage loss can be roughly estimated. Important effects on economic stability and global financial integration resist quantification. Giving up any possibility of devaluation is costly for some countries, negligible for others. And all must consider the implications of a reduced national role in providing lender of last resort facilities and backing for their banking systems.
Is dollarization, then, a better exchange rate regime, especially for developing countries? The answer for each country depends ultimately on its own unique characteristics, but a closer look at the pros and cons of dollarization offers some general guidance.
Box 2. What Is Seigniorage?
The ancient concept of seigniorage as a government's profit from issuing coinage that costs less to mint than its face value is essentially the same with paper currencies: abstracting from the minor cost of printing paper money, seigniorage is simply the increase in the volume of domestic currency.
Currency can be thought of as non-interest bearing debt, and the ability to issue it as a source of revenue for the monetary authorities. In addition, reserve requirements on banks may also be non-interest bearing (or be remunerated well below market rates levels) and thus contribute to seigniorage. Thus, the annual flow of seigniorage is frequently measured as the increase in base money (the sum of currency plus bank reserves).
As counterpart of the issuance of currency, the central bank acquires assets that do pay interest, such as foreign currency reserves, government securities, and loans to private banks. In a currency board system, for example, the central bank must acquire foreign reserves in an amount equal to the domestic currency issue. As a result of issuing non-interest bearing debt (currency) and holding interest-earning assets (foreign reserves, etc.) the central bank earns a gross profit, which is often also called seigniorage by central banks.
The Risk Premium
An immediate benefit from eliminating the risk of devaluation is reducing the country risk premium on foreign borrowing and obtaining lower interest rates for the government and private investors. Lower interest rates and more stability in international capital movements cut the cost of servicing the public debt, and encourage higher investment and economic growth.
The magnitude of this potential gain is hard to measure. Argentina, now using a currency board under which the peso rate is fixed at a ratio of one-to-one to the U.S. dollar, provides a good example of the difficulties. There, a higher interest rate for borrowing in pesos than for U. S. dollars persists as evidence that lenders see a risk that the exchange rate peg will be abandoned. Yet interest rates on dollar-denominated Argentine government and private securities also exceed those on industrial countries' debt, reflecting a risk of default by the country, or sovereign risk, on those securities.
With dollarization, the interest premium owing to devaluation risk would disappear, but the premium for sovereign risk would not. Since government and the private sector can choose to borrow in foreign or domestic currency in Argentina's heavily dollarized economy, they can already eliminate the cost of devaluation risk by borrowing in dollars. The key question, then, is: would full dollarization, by eliminating currency risk, substantially reduce the default risk premium on dollar-denominated debt?
Examining yields on bonds with different features can help disentangle how markets perceive sovereign, or default, risk as distinct from devaluation risk. Sovereign risk can be measured by the spread on dollar-denominated Argentine government bonds over U. S. Treasuries. This spread has tended to come down with time, but has still averaged 3.3 percentage points during 1997-98. Devaluation risk can be measured by the spread between peso- and dollar-denominated Eurobonds, which averaged 2.5 percent over the same period.
Arguments exist on both sides of the question of how much of the sovereign, or default, risk to attribute to devaluation risk. Although sovereign risk and devaluation risk move closely together, this does not establish a causal link from one to the other. In fact, it is plausible that most of both dollar and peso spreads are explained by common factors. For example, a global “flight to quality” would raise both the measured risk of default and risk of devaluation. In this case, dollarization would not help reduce dollar spreads very much.
In fully dollarized Panama, for instance, the absence of currency risk does not insulate the country from swings in market sentiment toward emerging markets generally. Moreover, since movements in Panama's spreads cannot reflect devaluation risk, the implication is that at least a part of Argentina's spread also cannot be explained by currency risk alone.
Devaluation risk might increase sovereign risk for several reasons. For example, governments acting to avoid currency crises may be increasing the risk of default. Mexico did this in 1994 by issuing too many dollar-denominated bonds or dollar-indexed bonds in its defense of the peso. Or a government may impose capital controls, causing other debtors to default on dollar-denominated debt, as Russia did in 1998, blocking private debtors' access to foreign currency, and preventing them from servicing their foreign debt obligations. Conversely, devaluation may reduce default risk by improving the domestic economy and the fiscal position, as it has in the European Monetary System. Even devaluations that initially slow the economy may improve longer-term prospects and thus reduce the risk of sovereign default.
Only by analyzing historical interest rate data for individual countries is it possible to get a sense of the magnitude of the reduction in the risk premium in the event of dollarization, inferring what markets assess as the probability of default on foreign debt in the absence of currency crisis risk.
Seigniorage
A country adopting a foreign currency as legal tender sacrifices its seigniorage, the profits accruing to the monetary authority from its right to issue currency. The immediate cost of this issuance can be significant, and it continues on an annual basis thereafter.
Dollarization involves two kinds of seigniorage loss. The first is the immediate “stock” cost: as the dollar is introduced and the domestic currency withdrawn from circulation, the monetary authorities must buy back the stock of domestic currency held by the public and banks, effectively returning to them the seigniorage that had accrued over time. Second, the monetary authorities would give up future seigniorage earnings stemming from the flow of new currency printed every year to satisfy the increase in money demand.
In the case of Argentina, the first, or stock, cost of dollarization would be the redemption of about $15 billion in domestic currency held outside the central bank, or about 4.0 percent of gross domestic product (GDP). In addition, the loss of seigniorage on account of the increase in currency demand would amount to about another $1.0 billion annually, or about 0.3 percent of GDP.
For countries that do not already have enough foreign reserves to buy up their domestic currency and thereby dollarize, the acquisition of the initial stock could add indirect costs. If the country lacks the credit to borrow the reserves, it would be forced to accumulate them through current account surpluses. The cost of this could be substantial in forgone investment if, as is usual for developing countries, the better policy would otherwise be to run some sustainable level of current account deficit.
The United States would get more seigniorage from dollarization in other countries. There is, therefore, a case for the U.S. authorities to share part or all of these additional seigniorage revenues with countries that adopt the U. S. dollar. A precedent exists in the arrangements between South Africa and three other states that use the rand (Lesotho, Namibia, and Swaziland). While the United States has no sharing arrangement with Panama or any other legally dollarized economy, there have been some initiatives in the U.S. Senate to consider legislation providing for seigniorage reimbursement.
Stability
Important as risk spreads and seigniorage are, dollarization may offer gains that, although not immediately observable, may provide larger benefits over time. In addition to raising developing countries' borrowing costs, currency crises wreak havoc on the domestic economy. In Mexico, GDP fell by 7 percent in 1995, and the Asian countries affected by currency crises witnessed recessions in the range of 7-15 percent of GDP in 1998. Most of the severely affected countries in recent crises devalued and floated their exchange rate, but even countries with currency boards such as Hong Kong SAR and Argentina suffered fierce speculative attacks that, although weathered successfully, dealt them serious economic setbacks.
Dollarization will not eliminate the risk of external crises, since investors may flee because of problems of weakness in a country's budget position or the soundness of the financial system. This sort of “debt crisis” can be as damaging as any other, and indeed, Panama has experienced several.
Nevertheless, dollarization holds the promise of a steadier market sentiment as the elimination of exchange rate risk would tend to limit the incidence and magnitude of crisis and contagion episodes. Moreover, large swings in international capital flows cause sharp business cycle fluctuations in emerging economies even when they do not involve balance of payments crises.
Effect on Trade and Financial Links
A powerful but still longer-term argument for full, legal dollarization is that it makes economic integration easier with the rest of the world, and insulation of the domestic financial system correspondingly more difficult. Dollarization may establish a firm basis for a sound financial sector, and thus promote strong and steady economic growth. The argument here is that dollarization is perceived as an irreversible institutional change toward low inflation, fiscal responsibility, and transparency.
Furthermore, dollarization may contribute to greater economic integration than otherwise would be possible with the United States, or any other country whose currency is adopted. A number of studies have found evidence that Canadian provinces tend to be more integrated in trade volume and price level differences among themselves than with U.S. states that are closer geographically, trading in the order of twenty times more among themselves than with nearby U. S. states. The use of a common currency may thus be a vital factor in market integration, given the fairly low transaction costs and restrictions to trade across the U.S.-Canada border.
Dollarization could also bring about a closer integration in financial markets. One of the most profound effects of Panama's dollarization is the close integration of its banking system with that of the United States and indeed with the rest of the world, particularly since a major liberalization in 1969-70.
Exit Option
With full dollarization, a country completely gives up control of monetary and exchange rate policy. This may seem identical to currency board arrangements, since a country with a currency board cannot devalue. However, there is some scope for exit from the pegged exchange rate with a currency board, if only under extreme circumstances. Indeed, the elimination of this risk of devaluation is the main purpose of full dollarization.
Benefiting from Devaluation. Large shocks, such as a big jump in world oil prices or fall in the price of an important export, may require countries to devalue. Otherwise, they must absorb these shocks through lower nominal wages and adjustments in domestic prices. Substantial recession may then be unavoidable, particularly for economies with rigid labor markets.
Experiences such as departures from the gold standard and the 1994 devaluation of the CFA franc suggest that an exit option may have great value in the presence of extreme, unexpected shocks. During the Great Depression, for example, the industrial countries that fared best were those that exited earliest from the fixed exchange regime of the time--the gold standard. Argentina was one of them, suffering only a relatively minor economic setback by abandoning convertibility early, then actively stimulating the economy through monetary policy to offset the deflationary impact of capital outflows.
The countries of the CFA franc zone of West and Central Africa are recent examples of states with firmly pegged currencies that have successfully devalued to overcome severe external shocks and sluggish growth. The 14-nation franc zone resembles a currency board, with a fully convertible currency and an exchange rate fixed at par with the French franc from 1948 until 1994. From the second half of the 1980s into the early 1990s, output in the CFA franc zone stagnated as the French franc rose in value against the U.S. dollar, the CFA franc appreciated accordingly, the terms of trade deteriorated, and labor costs rose sharply. In 1994, the 14 countries resorted to a 50 percent devaluation, achieving a turnaround in higher output, exports, and investment.
Finally, countries with highly credible policymakers can also be well placed to benefit from devaluation, since the increase in expectations of inflation is likely to be lower than in countries with records of loose fiscal and monetary policies. For example, the CFA franc zone devaluation caused little inflation, occurring, as it did, against a long history of exclusive reliance on internal adjustments to deal with economic shocks.
Devaluations with High Cost. These examples suggest countries may pay a high price for foregoing the option to exit from a fixed exchange rate arrangement. The reverse is true where monetary policy has been poorly managed and expectations of inflation are highly sensitive to the exchange rate. In these countries, devaluation can sharply raise domestic prices, making it hard to achieve changes in the real exchange rate. Similarly, in countries that have become so dollarized that the dollar is often the de facto unit of account, devaluation quickly raises domestic prices, again limiting the effectiveness of devaluations. In fact, these were central reasons why Argentina adopted a currency board.
Countries with a high degree of financial asset dollarization have a further reason to avoid devaluation. If a country's banks or corporations receive large amounts of dollar-denominated lending, devaluation sharply worsens their balance sheets. Even if banks on-lend to domestic firms in dollars, maintaining matched risks in terms of currency on their books, they still carry a substantial currency risk. A sharp depreciation of the domestic currency would cause a large drop in revenues in dollar terms for the banks' clients, reducing their ability to service dollar debts.
As the currency crises in Mexico in 1994 and East Asia in 1997 demonstrated, when there are weak banking systems and large foreign exchange exposures in the private sector, the financial health of banks and firms is at such risk following a devaluation that economic activity is severely disrupted. Thus, devaluation as a policy option may be prohibitively costly for highly dollarized economies, and moving to full dollarization would not entail the loss of an important policy tool.
Lender of Last Resort Function and Financial System Stability
While full dollarization eliminates vulnerability of the banking system to the risk of devaluation, it does not eradicate all sources of banking crisis. And when they occur, full dollarization may well impair the country's lender-of-last-resort function and hence the central bank's response to financial system emergencies.
The central bank's role in operating a discount window to provide short-term liquidity must here be distinguished from its role as the ultimate guarantor of the stability of the financial and payments systems in the event of a systemic bank run. Dollarization should not greatly impede the ability of the authorities to provide short-term liquidity to the system or assistance to individual banks in distress. Such facilities are available if the central bank (or its replacement) saves the necessary funds in advance or perhaps secures lines of credit with international banks.
In contrast, the government loses some ability to respond to a sudden run on bank deposits throughout the entire system. In the case of a generalized loss of confidence, the authorities would be unable to guarantee the whole payments system or to fully back bank deposits. Ultimately, the ability to print money as needed is what allows a central bank to guarantee beyond any doubt that all claims (in domestic currency) will be fully met under any circumstances. Once the ability to print money ceases to exist, limits to the lender-of-last-resort function appear.A fully dollarized country that had already spent its foreign currency reserves to redeem its stock of domestic currency might well lack the resources to respond.
A Cushion for Currency Boards. Currency boards can create base money only to the extent that they accumulate reserves, so they are almost as tightly constrained as the monetary authorities would be in a dollarized economy. In important currency board cases, however, the authorities have allowed themselves some flexibility to create money that is not fully backed on the margin, partly to be able to deal with banking crises. In the case of the run on the Argentine peso during the 1995 “tequila” crisis, for example, the Argentine monetary authorities were able to partially accommodate the conversion of peso deposits into dollar deposits held abroad as well as into dollar cash.
By temporarily reducing their reserve coverage of the money base, they could increase the issuance of dollar cash and provide the dollar credits the banks needed to stay afloat. In the wake of the 1997 attack on the Hong Kong dollar, the Hong Kong Monetary Authority introduced in September 1998 a discount window to provide short-term liquidity to banks in a more flexible way and at lower cost than under previous arrangements. The new system is expected to reduce the volatility in short-term domestic interest rates. The maximum volume of rediscounts is limited, however, and the Hong Kong Monetary Authority fully backs rediscounts with foreign exchange.
The scope for accommodation to bank runs in a currency board is inevitably restricted. Indeed, even without the restrictions imposed by a currency board system, the ability of a central bank to find a way out of a financial crisis by resorting to printing money alone is limited. The injection of liquidity into the banking system to keep it from defaulting on deposits may only lead to greater pressure on foreign reserves or the exchange rate.
Conclusions
Summing up, the main pros and cons of dollarization are as follows:
Advantages
· Dollarization avoids currency and balance of payments crises. Without a domestic currency there is no possibility of a sharp depreciation, or of sudden capital outflows motivated by fears of devaluation.
· A closer integration with both the global and U. S. economies would follow from lower transaction costs and an assured stability of prices in dollar terms.
· By definitively rejecting the possibility of inflationary finance through dollarization, countries might also strengthen their financial institutions and create positive sentiment toward investment, both domestic and international.
Disadvantages
· Countries are likely to be reluctant to abandon their own currencies, symbols of their nationhood, particularly in favor of those of other nations. As a practical matter, political resistance is nearly certain, and likely to be strong.
· From an economic point of view, the right to issue a country's currency provides its government with seigniorage revenues, which show up as central bank profits and are transferred to the government. They would be lost to dollarizing countries and gained by the United States unless it agreed to share them.
· A dollarizing country would relinquish any possibility of having an autonomous monetary and exchange rate policy, including the use of central bank credit to provide liquidity support to its banking system in emergencies.
What is the balance of costs and benefits of full dollarization? The answers may seem frustratingly two-handed. This is inevitable, given the complexity of the issue and the current state of knowledge about it. The potential benefits of lower interest rates and the cost of forgone seigniorage revenues can at least be estimated. But many of the most important considerations, such as the value of keeping an exit option and lender of last resort protections, are virtually unquantifiable.
Which countries are likely to benefit from dollarization? The most obvious are those already highly integrated with the United States in trade and financial relations. Yet most countries in Latin America are quite different from the United States in their economic structure and would probably not benefit greatly from dollarization unless accompanied by deep market integration, as in the European Union.
The current discussion centers on a different group of candidates: emerging market economies exposed to volatile capital flows but not necessarily close, in an economic sense, to the United States. For this group, the more the U.S. dollar is already used in their domestic goods and financial markets, the smaller the advantage of keeping a national currency. For an economy that is already extremely dollarized, seigniorage revenues would be small (and the cost of purchasing the remaining stock of domestic currency also would be small), the exposures of banks and businesses would make devaluation financially risky, and the exchange rate would not serve as a policy instrument because prices would be “sticky” in dollar terms. In such cases, dollarization may offer more benefits than costs.
Подобные документы
Выявление стилистических особенностей газетных текстов, изучение их структуры в английском языке. Особенности и подходы к переводу английских заголовков. Изучение основных способов перевода английских газетно-информационных текстов и их систематизация.
дипломная работа [110,4 K], добавлен 14.05.2013Художественный перевод трех текстов с английского языка на русский. Особенности получения высшего образования в Великобритании. Биография и путь к науке А. Эйнштейна. Основные моменты обучения в Хабаровском институте железнодорожного машиностроения.
контрольная работа [20,9 K], добавлен 30.10.2009Определение частей речи, которыми являются слова с окончанием –s в английских предложениях. Перевод предложений с выделением определений, выраженных существительным. Определение видовременных форм глагола с указанием их инфинитива, перевод текстов.
контрольная работа [14,1 K], добавлен 01.07.2010Специальная теория перевода и понятие адекватности экономического дискурса. Особенности перевода английских экономических текстов: на уровне лексических единиц, на грамматическом и стилистическом уровне. Перевод заголовков, фразеологизмов, клише, метафор.
дипломная работа [87,3 K], добавлен 11.05.2012Типы новообразований в лексическом составе языка. Виды, условия и причины иноязычных лексических заимствований, классификация их способов. Особенности употребления английских заимствований музыкальной тематики на материале газетно-информационных текстов.
курсовая работа [490,9 K], добавлен 02.02.2012Business as a combination of types of activities: production, distribution and sale, obtaining economic profit. Basic types and functions of banks. The principle of equilibrium prices and financial management. The use of accounting in the organization.
контрольная работа [17,8 K], добавлен 31.01.2011Перевод английских текстов и активного словарного запаса на русский и украинский языки в письменном виде. Ответы на вопросы по тексту. Перевод утверждений и определение их правдивости или ложности. Составление вопросов по тексту на английском языке.
контрольная работа [41,9 K], добавлен 28.01.2012Definition and stages of business cycles, their causes and the characteristic of kinds. Types and a continuity of business cycles. Kondratyev's wave. A role of cycles in stabilization of a policy of the state. Great depression as an economic crisis.
реферат [130,5 K], добавлен 20.03.2011Технический перевод в современном обществе. Синтаксис, грамматика и морфология научных текстов. Особенности и способы перевода на русский язык английских терминов механоремонтной литературы. Ложные друзья переводчика в сфере автомобильной лексики.
дипломная работа [61,6 K], добавлен 07.03.2014Понятие и семантические группы неологизмов в современном английском языке. Особенности и трудности перевода английских неологизмов на русский язык на примере современной прессы. О некоторых английских лексических новообразованиях в области электроники.
курсовая работа [41,9 K], добавлен 06.11.2012